Want to share your content on R-bloggers? click here if you have a blog, or here if you don't.
Specifics of statistical factor models and of a particular implementation of them.
Previously
Posts that are background for this one include:
- Three things factor models do
- Factor models of variance in finance
- The BurStFin R package
- The quality of variance matrix estimation
The problem
Someone asked me some questions about the statistical factor model in BurStFin
. The response “I don’t know either” didn’t seem quite optimal.
The method
My way of getting to the answers was:
- Go back to the mathematical model
- Create a small, simple data example
Small data examples can be an effective way to clarify your thoughts. We’ll see that “small” means small for us, not necessarily small for the computer. That those can be different is part of the power of R.
The model
The post “Factor models of variance in finance” said:
In matrix notation a factor model is:
V = B’FB + D
This notation hides a lot of details:
- V is a square of numbers (of size number-of-assets by number-of-assets).
- B is a rectangle of sensitivities of size number-of-factors by number-of-assets.
- F is the variance matrix of the factors (of size number-of-factors by number-of-factors).
- D is a diagonal matrix (all off-diagonal elements are zero) of the idiosyncratic variance of each asset. The total size of D is number-of-assets by number-of-assets, but there are only number-of-assets values that are not zero.
(end quote)
But that is the model in terms of the variance matrix. The more fundamental model is in terms of the returns. We can write that as:
r = fB + e
where:
- r is a matrix of returns of size number-of-times by number-of-assets.
- f is a matrix of factor returns of size number-of-times by number-of-factors.
- B is a matrix of sensitivities of size number-of-factors by number-of-assets.
- e is a matrix of idiosyncratic (specific) returns of size number-of-times by number-of-assets.
The return equation looks suspiciously like a multivariate linear regression. In fact that is precisely how macroeconomic factor models are built. You could think of “f” as being the history of market returns, interest rates and so on; you would then do regressions to get the coefficients in B.
But we are doing a statistical factor model. The more proper name is a latent factor model. That is, we don’t get to see the factors — we only infer them. Since we are imagining the existence of phantoms, we might as well assume they are nice: we assume that they are uncorrelated with each other, and each has variance one. This means that “F” disappears from the first equation.
An example
Let’s use R to build a 2-factor model for 3 assets.
generate variance
The first thing to do is create a matrix of factor sensitivities:
set.seed(3) realfac <- matrix(runif(6, -1,1), nrow=3)
The first command sets the seed for the random number generator so that the result will be reproducible. The second command creates a 3 by 2 matrix of random uniforms between -1 and 1.
It is traditional for there to be orthogonality between factors in statistical factor models. We can achieve that in our case by using the residuals from a linear regression:
realfac[,2] <- resid(lm(realfac[,2] ~ realfac[,1]))
The sensitivities are:
> realfac [,1] [,2] [1,] -0.6639169 -0.1563740 [2,] 0.6150328 -0.0802644 [3,] -0.2301153 0.2366384
Now we can create specific variances and the actual variance matrix:
realspec <- c(.04, .12, .32) realvar <- realfac %*% t(realfac) diag(realvar) <- diag(realvar) + realspec
The variance matrix is:
> realvar [,1] [,2] [,3] [1,] 0.5052385 -0.3957794 0.1157734 [2,] -0.3957794 0.5047077 -0.1605221 [3,] 0.1157734 -0.1605221 0.4289508
generate returns
We’ll generate returns with a multivariate normal distribution with the variance that we’ve created. We’ll use a function from the MASS
package to do that:
require(MASS) retOneGo <- mvrnorm(1e6, mu=c(0,0,0), Sigma=realvar) colnames(retOneGo) <- paste0("A", 1:3)
This creates a matrix that has 3 columns and 1 million rows. The last line names the assets.
The gore
We can now estimate a factor model from the returns:
require(BurStFin) sfmOneGo <- factor.model.stat(retOneGo, weight=1, output="factor", range=c(2,2))
Often this function is called by just giving it the matrix of returns, but here we are overriding the default value of some arguments. By default the estimation uses time weights; saying “weight=1
” is the easiest way of specifying equal weights. The default is to return the estimated variance matrix, here we are asking for the object containing the pieces to be returned. Finally we are demanding that exactly 2 factors be used.
The object is:
> sfmOneGo $loadings [,1] [,2] A1 0.8617398 -0.3310512 A2 -0.8883301 0.2148856 A3 0.5923341 0.8038865 attr(,"scaled:scale") [1] 0.728824 1.116636 $uniquenesses A1 A2 A3 0.14780966 0.16469372 0.03188738 $sdev A1 A2 A3 0.7119102 0.7111206 0.6551395 $timestamp [1] "Sun Nov 11 10:07:19 2012" $call factor.model.stat(x = retOneGo, weights = 1, output = "factor", range.factors = c(2, 2)) attr(,"class") [1] "statfacmodBurSt"
The components that pertain to the actual model are:
loadings
uniquenesses
sdev
sensitivities
The B in the equations above is:
> t(sfmOneGo$sdev * sfmOneGo$loadings) A1 A2 A3 [1,] 0.6134813 -0.6317098 0.3880615 [2,] -0.2356787 0.1528096 0.5266578
The operation to get this is to multiply each row of loadings
by the corresponding element of sdev
and then take the transpose.
specific variances
The uniquenesses are the fractions of the asset variances that are not explained by the factors. Thus the specific variances are the square of sdev
times uniquenesses
:
> sfmOneGo$sdev^2 * sfmOneGo$uniquenesses A1 A2 A3 0.07491232 0.08328438 0.01368631
orthogonality
Now let’s have a hunt for orthogonality. It is in the loadings
:
> cov.wt(sfmOneGo$loadings, center=FALSE) $cov [,1] [,2] [1,] 9.412928e-01 4.163336e-17 [2,] 4.163336e-17 4.010021e-01 $center [1] 0 $n.obs [1] 3
Note that the variance is the wrong thing to do here because it subtracts off the means:
> var(sfmOneGo$loadings) [,1] [,2] [1,] 0.88794845 -0.06484563 [2,] -0.06484563 0.32217545
The sensitivities including the standard deviations are not orthogonal:
> cov.wt(sfmOneGo$loadings * sfmOneGo$sdev, center=FALSE) $cov [,1] [,2] [1,] 0.46300419 -0.01837012 [2,] -0.01837012 0.17813184 $center [1] 0 $n.obs [1] 3
This suggests that perhaps an option could be added to get orthogonality on this scale.
accuracy
We can see how close the estimate of the variance matrix is to the actual value. The estimated variance is:
> fitted(sfmOneGo) A1 A2 A3 A1 0.5068161 -0.4235562 0.1139464 A2 -0.4235562 0.5056925 -0.1646639 A3 0.1139464 -0.1646639 0.4416465 attr(,"number.of.factors") [1] 2 attr(,"timestamp") [1] "Sun Nov 11 10:07:19 2012"
The difference between the estimated variance and its true value is:
> fitted(sfmOneGo) - realvar A1 A2 A3 A1 0.001577602 -0.0277767353 -0.001826927 A2 -0.027776735 0.0009847477 -0.004141787 A3 -0.001826927 -0.0041417871 0.012695676 attr(,"number.of.factors") [1] 2 attr(,"timestamp") [1] "Sun Nov 11 10:07:19 2012"
The dfference between the estimate and the actual is small but not especially close to zero.
More gore (factor returns)
Now we’ll use the model we just estimated to simulate another set of returns. This time, though, we will create factor returns and idiosyncratic returns, and then put them together.
realFacRet <- matrix(rnorm(2e6), ncol=2) realFacSpec <- matrix(rnorm(3e6, sd=rep(sfmOneGo$sdev * sqrt(sfmOneGo$uniquenesses), each=1e6)), ncol=3) retFR <- realFacRet %*% t(sfmOneGo$sdev * sfmOneGo$loadings) + realFacSpec colnames(retFR) <- paste0("B", 1:3)
We use the new return matrix to estimate a factor model:
sfmFR <- factor.model.stat(retFR, weight=1, output="factor", range=c(2,2))
Now we can compare the sensitivities of the two models:
> t(sfmOneGo$sdev * sfmOneGo$loadings) A1 A2 A3 [1,] 0.6134813 -0.6317098 0.3880615 [2,] -0.2356787 0.1528096 0.5266578 attr(,"scaled:scale") [1] 0.728824 1.116636 > t(sfmFR$sdev * sfmFR$loadings) B1 B2 B3 [1,] 0.6305413 -0.6505287 0.3757351 [2,] -0.2284438 0.1400226 0.5476813 attr(,"scaled:scale") [1] 0.7171768 1.1040259
The "scaled:scale"
attribute can be ignored.
We can estimate the factor returns implied by the newly estimated factor model. We have a multivariate regression but it is turned sideways from before. There are number-of-times individual regressions to do. Each of them have number-of-assets observations and number-of-factors coefficients to estimate. The coefficients will be our estimates of the factor returns.
As preparation, we create the matrix of sensitivities:
sensFRt <- sfmFR$sdev * sfmFR$loadings
Estimating a million regressions is more than we really want to do. Let’s do just the first 1000 observations in the return matrix:
estFacRet <- t(coef(lm(t(retFR[1:1000,]) ~ 0 + sensFRt)))
This does a linear regression (lm
) with the transpose of the first 1000 returns as the response and the sensitivities as the explanatory variables with no intercept. We then get the transpose of the coefficients of that regression.
We see that the variance matrix of the estimated factor returns is close to the identity — as we want:
> var(estFacRet) sensFRt1 sensFRt2 sensFRt1 1.015795719 0.007103762 sensFRt2 0.007103762 1.064414085
and that the variance of the errors of the factor return estimates is smaller:
> var(estFacRet - realFacRet[1:1000,]) sensFRt1 sensFRt2 sensFRt1 0.07660990 -0.03752711 sensFRt2 -0.03752711 0.06754317
Plotting the errors shows that there can be fairly large discrepancies however.
Figure 1: The estimated factor returns minus the true factor returns for the first 1000 observations.
It seems feasible to suppose that the regressions to get factor returns would be better in practice since there will be a large number of assets — the current case is estimating 2 parameters with only 3 observations. However, the estimation of the sensitivities will be worse since there will not be a million time points with which to estimate them (and the market is not going to follow the model anyway).
Figures 2 and 3 compare the true and estimated factor returns.
Figure 2: True and estimated returns for factor 1.
Figure 3: True and estimated returns for factor 2.
Questions
I’m thinking that statistical factor models have no advantages over a Ledoit-Wolf shrinkage estimate (var.shrink.eqcor
in BurStFin
). Hence enhancing factor.model.stat
is a waste of time. Why am I wrong?
One of the features of the variance estimators in BurStFin
is that they allow missing values. There is no guarantee that missing values are handled especially well. Would someone like to research how they should be handled? Please?
R-bloggers.com offers daily e-mail updates about R news and tutorials about learning R and many other topics. Click here if you're looking to post or find an R/data-science job.
Want to share your content on R-bloggers? click here if you have a blog, or here if you don't.